logo

35 pages 1 hour read

Mike Davis

Planet of Slums

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2005

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Chapters 1-3Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Chapter 1 Summary: “The Urban Climacteric”

An epigraph by Onookome Okome sets the tone for the chapter and the book: “We live in the age of the city. The city is everything to us—it consumes us, and for that reason we glorify it” (1).

Davis begins the first chapter with a proclamation: Urban populations surpass rural populations for the first time in history. This unprecedented rate of urbanization is occurring faster than 20th century experts predicted, particularly in China, India, and Brazil. More people became city dwellers during the 1980s in China than in all of Europe during the 19th century. This new growth has created megacities (8 million or more inhabitants) and hypercities (20 million or more) and has raised the threat of poverty for people in these megalopolises and those in the smaller, second-tier cities, places lacking resources and planning to provide citizens adequate services.

People born in rural areas are more frequently moving to urban ones, while the growth of cities is occurring so fast that city sprawl often incorporates rural areas as it grows. Many regions of the world (from India to Indonesia to Latin America) are experiencing a shift in the divide between urban and rural, falling into what urban theorist Thomas Sieverts called in-between cities—weblike places with no center and no peripheries. 

While large cities in Europe and Asia (particularly in China, Korea, and Taiwan) have manufacturing export machines to support the population, many cities in the developing world lack that industry. As a result, the population of a city has become uncoupled from its Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Some scholars attribute this to capitalism’s tendency to delink production growth and employment, but Davis argues that in Africa, Latin America, the Middle East, and most of South Asia, urbanization without growth is “the legacy of a global political conjuncture—the worldwide debt crisis of the late 1970s and the subsequent IMF-led restructuring of Third World economies in the 1980s” (14).

The structural adjustment programs (SAPs) of the IMF pushed agrarian and agricultural producers into a global commodity-driven market. Rural farmers could not compete in said market, which led to increasing financial vulnerability—for instance, through drought inflation or medical costs. In response to this problem, along with civil wars and warlords, cities harvested rural areas, creating overurbanization, “one of the unexpected tracks down which a neoliberal world order is shunting the future” (16).

19th century economists and political theorists Karl Marx and Max Weber saw industrialized cities like Berlin and Chicago as potential lynchpins of a coming utopia. Instead, however, many new large cities resemble Victorian Dublin, which was essentially a slum. Housing shortages mean people in these burgeoning cities resort to self-built shanties, informal rentals, or sidewalks. In many areas, the unhoused population (often comprised of migrant workers from rural areas) grows at exponential rates. For example, Karachi’s squatter population doubles every decade. Out of the 500,000 people that move to Delhi each year, 400,000 end up in slums. By 2015, India’s slum population would number over 10 million. Planning expert Gautam Chatterjee writes, "If such a trend continues unabated, we will have only slums and no cities” (18).

Chapter 2 Summary: “The Prevalence of Slums”

In 2003, the UN Humans Settlements Programme published The Challenge of Slums, a report on urban living conditions and poverty. This report issues a clear warning, much like climate researchers have, that the future may be untenable.

The Challenge of Slums describes slums as “characterized by overcrowding, poor or informal housing, inadequate access to safe water and sanitation, and insecurity of tenure” (22-23). By this restrictive definition, UN researchers estimated that there were more than one billion citizens in slums in 2005. Davis is quick to point out that it is difficult to get accurate numbers because often poor populations are undercounted.

At the time of Davis’s writing, there were over 200,000 slums on earth. The five largest slum areas (Dhaka, Kolkata, Karachi, Mumbai, and Delhi) had around 15,000 slum communities, whose population exceeded 20 million. These are megaslums, where “shanty­towns and squatter communities merge in continuous belts of informal housing and poverty, usually on the urban periphery” (26).

Those in unstable housing have often been forced into slums to have access to the job market—a function of city shape. In American cities, large poor populations typically live in the city center, or the inner city. European cities are hubs, with migrant and unemployed individuals often in low-cost high-rise apartments around the edges of a city. In the developing world, poverty can be centrally or peripherally located, relying on tenements and rental housing from governments reluctant to spend money on such projects. A chawl, for example, is a city housing space in Mumbai that often crams six people into 15 square meters (160 square feet); the bathrooms are shared between six families. There are many variations of the same insufficient and unhealthy housing across the globe.

One of the new developments of urban growth is horizontalization: Cities are bigger geographically because low-cost housing that exists on the edges of the city always stretches further.

Davis categorizes residents of slums: Squatters, or people who take possession of a land that is not theirs; urban pirates, or squatters encouraged by landowners hoping to get state compensation and sometimes infrastructural development; renters, who lack political agency and whose presence often widens the gap between middle and lower classes; and finally the undefinable and usually unstudied and uncounted edge of the city. This liminal area, where the urban collides with the rural, is typically ignored by regulation—for instance, in China, Beijing’s garment sweatshops hide there, while in Bangalore, cheap labor can be found on the fringes, without much oversight by the state. Children that live there, without access to education, are often recruited into gangs or paramilitary groups.

Chapter 3 Summary: “The Treason of the State”

Davis posits that “before considering why Third World cities and their slums grew so fast in the second half of the twentieth century, it is first necessary to understand why they grew so slowly in the first half” (50). Most megacities follow the same trajectory: slow growth followed by an abrupt spurt that began in the 1950s and 1960s and continues to this day.

One cause of this was European colonialism, which often denied Indigenous populations urban land ownership or residence. The extreme of this example was South African Apartheid, which uprooted inner-city communities of color, evicting them from white areas. British imperialists were the world’s greatest purveyor of slums—their policies forced many colonized peoples to live in poorly built, unsafe (both infrastructurally and medically) housing situations. Another cause of the sudden rise in city population were mid-20th century revolutions and civil wars, sometimes covertly influenced by would-be imperialist powers. For example, during the Vietnam War, the US forced the urbanization of South Vietnam, which made the country’s population less spread out and more centralized.

In response to the sudden influx of poor into cities, government policies denying city access to non-urban dwellers became commonplace. For instance, after the 1949 Chinese Revolution made cities a beacon to job-hungry peasants from the countryside, the Stalinist Mao regime created stringent regulations around internal migration, supporting the urban proletariat over rural workers. Similarly, in Latin America, post-WWII industrialization drove many poor urban dwellers from rental housing to squatting on the edges of cities. In response, the government launched crackdowns on informal housing as a way to actively support the property-owning middle class. In another example, in sub-Saharan Africa, the influx of many new city dwellers—primarily farmers—led the government to impose rigid policies that forced these peasants to deliver farm goods below market value or face harsh rural taxation—a dual pressure that highlights the urban bias prevalent in African development.

Despite all of this, Davis argues that slums could have been avoided. For instance, Cuba’s National Institute of Savings and Housing had an avant-garde approach to urban development in the early 1960s, undertaking a national effort to rehouse people living in poverty. Similar models were attempted in Brazil and Tanzania, offering glimpses of what could have been. Instead, however, “in the rest of the Third World, the idea of an interventionist state strongly committed to social housing and job development seems either a hallucination or a bad joke, because governments long ago abdicated any serious effort to combat slums and redress urban marginality” (62).

Governments are doubly guilty: They have failed to safely house poor urban dwellers while aiding middle-class poaching of public or state-subsidized housing. In Vietnam, for example, civil servants or army members entitled to municipal housing often sublet their units. In general, middle-class city residents and the urban elite are often much more adept at avoiding taxation that detrimentally affects poor people. Davis lays some of the blame at the feet of the IMF, which “everywhere advocates regressive user fees and charges for public services but never proposes counterpart efforts to tax wealth, conspicuous consumption, or real estate” (68).

Chapters 1-3 Analysis

Chapter 1 has three functions. After articulating the problem of rising urban population growth and the resulting precarity and instability of housing available for poor people migrating to cities, Davis considers why the situation came to be. His central argument is that after the devastation of colonization ended, the IMF—and later governments themselves—continued many of the same imperialist policies that exacerbated inequalities and prevented governments from fostering functioning societies. Ostensibly, the IMF is the financial watchdog of the developing world, helping countries overburdened by sovereign debt; however, in practice, the IMF’s debt restructuring policies force austerity measures that deny the urban poor services in favor of GDP primarily being spent on repayment. As a result, cities become primarily slums, as Davis’s statistics and studies demonstrate. Davis ends on a powerful note, quoting urban planning expert Gautam Chatterjee: "If such a trend continues unabated, we will have only slums and no cities” (18).

The second chapter defines different types of slums into four categories. First are traditional inner-city slums, where the rich parts of city surround a hollowed-out center stricken by poverty, tenement housing, and safety concerns. The second type of slum is “pirate urbanization,” which is when building and property owners promote squatting by unhoused workers, profiting either by getting compensation from the government or by attracting government building projects that buy them out. Third are slums composed of “invisible renters,” who face the unequal power dynamics of the landlord-renter model. Many renters lack the political agency to improve their position, which widens the gap between middle and lower classes, and sometimes pits poor people against other poor people. The last category of slum Davis calls undefinable, unstudied, and uncounted: It is the expanding edge of a city where the urban collides with the rural.

In Chapter 3, Davis explores how governments have reacted to growing urban populations. Typically, in the developing world, policies are aimed at curbing access to the city for the influx of people in poverty—a reaction that prioritizes the interests of landowners and business elites. The resulting laws, regulations, and restrictions have led to the increase of unsafe and unhealthy slum living. However, Davis argues that this harsh reality was not inevitable, using communist countries like Cuba as a counterpoint. Readers may find this line of argument objectionable, given Cuba’s repressive regime; Davis, however, sees Cuba’s example as a lost opportunity:” with a handful of exceptions, then, the postcolonial state has comprehensively betrayed its original promises to the urban poor” (69).

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text