48 pages • 1 hour read
Marc ReisnerA modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
In Chapter 8, Reisner returns to the Colorado River basin but this time focuses on Arizona’s water dilemma. To meet its growing water demand, the state began to overdraft its groundwater. By the 1960s, the annual overdraft reached 2.2-4 million acre-feet per year, resulting in the chronic depletion of the state’s groundwater and land subsidence (sinking of the Earth’s surface).
By the early 1950s, California had begun to use more than its allotted amount from the Colorado River. Out of sheer desperation, Arizona approached the Supreme Court to try and get the water allotment issue resolved between the basin states. The case, Arizona v. California, finally settled the longstanding dispute. It was one of the longest-running lawsuits ever in the Supreme Court, with the Court ruling mostly in Arizona’s favor. The most surprising ruling was that the Interior Secretary was not bound by the law of prior appropriation. This meant that during droughts or other natural calamities, the Interior Secretary would decide how much Colorado water each basin state received.
During the court case, Arizona was also seeking congressional approval for the Central Arizona Project (CAP), which would divert Colorado River water into the state’s more populous areas and to farmland where groundwater was depleted. The latter was the project’s primary purpose. After negotiations with California, the project’s construction finally began. Reisner emphasizes how the project makes little economic sense because of the territory it traverses. The presence of steep hills increases the project’s costs because of the energy required to pump the water up these hills.
The Bureau had to contend with the reality that the Colorado might dry up, something they downplayed to the public for many years. This led the Bureau and the basin states, especially the upper basin states, to consider water importation ideas from the Columbia River. While one of Washington State’s senators prevented further exploration of this plan, the Bureau did not give up. It wanted to build dams in the Grand Canyon whose surplus power revenues would eventually go to pay for other projects (such as water importation projects). Conservationists, including the Sierra Club, fiercely opposed the construction of these dams, and the projects were eventually killed.
Reisner concludes that the Central Arizona Project (CAP) could make Arizona’s water crisis worse. There is little doubt that the Colorado Basin will eventually enter a permanent drought. When this happens, the clause stipulating California will receive CAP water will kick in before farmers and city-dwellers in Arizona receive a single drop. In addition, the CAP water was more expensive than what farmers were willing to pay.
This chapter focuses on two political administrations, Jimmy Carter’s and Ronald Reagan’s, and their effect on water distribution policy. Carter, from the start of his presidency, declared war on the “courtesy” system (also called the pork barrel by its critics), which is the business of trading favors in Congress. Carter wanted to balance the federal budget, an ambitious goal considering the country’s debt was approaching a trillion dollars. One of the first items Carter wanted to cut was funding for all water projects. This hit list leaked and caused a massive uproar in Congress. To circumvent this list, the House Appropriations Committee introduced a public works appropriations bill that included most of the projects Carter wanted cut and added funding for new projects. Carter eventually signed the bill because “he had underestimated Congress’s passion for dams and overestimated his ability to move the rest of his legislative program forward” (321). This was not the only time during his presidency that Carter signed bills that went against his water reform ideas to help other legislative issues pass.
Carter tried to enforce the Reclamation Act. An investigation by his administration found that most violators were California and Arizona farmers. When Carter’s administration tried to enforce the law and curb these violations, growers in California managed to lobby for an amendment to the act in the early 1980s. This amendment raised the acreage limit to 960 and removed all leasing and residency restrictions. The growers, in return, paid (although this is questionable) the actual cost for water delivered to lands beyond the new acreage limit.
Reagan also tried to reform policy related to water projects. For example, his budget director wanted to recover 100% of both the capital and the operating costs of new navigation projects from those who benefited. There were also discussions about making states pay larger shares of flood-control dam costs, something even Carter had not suggested. The Reagan administration also wanted to see states contribute to Reclamation projects from the start. Under Reagan, Congress did not pass any new authorization bills due to the federal government’s debt and Reagan threatening to veto such bills. Reisner notes that the single greatest blow to the pork barrel was “the very thing it helped produce: an uncontrollable tide of national debt” (331).
In Chapter 10, Reisner looks at the history of California’s State Water Project. The project’s origins lay with the San Joaquin Valley, which, by the late 1950s, was one of the most agriculturally productive places on the planet. The valley also had a massive issue: Its groundwater was being chronically depleted due to agriculture. Rather than regulating groundwater pumping, the state decided to build “a huge project to bring in more water from somewhere else” (342). The project was based on deception. The Governor of California, Edmund (Pat) G. Brown, knew that voters, particularly in Southern California, were unlikely to vote in favor of the project due to its cost. As such, Brown lied about the cost, helping to get the necessary votes.
Brown was also dishonest about how much water could be purchased through the initial bonds. Most Californians thought they were purchasing four million acre-feet, when the project’s initial facilities could only deliver about half that amount. By underfunding the bond issue, Brown failed to consider the effects of inflation. To deliver the rest of the project’s water acreage would cost two to five times more than the original bond.
When California’s Department of Water Resources began to circulate contracts for water from the project, few farmers in the San Joaquin Valley were willing to sign them. The irrigation water was barely subsidized. It would cost between $25 and $45 per acre-foot compared to Bureau water, which was never more than $7.50. In many places, you could still pump groundwater for $15 per acre-foot. The farmers wanted the water, but only if the price was the “energy cost of delivery” (367). They felt this price was reasonable since it was surplus water. Los Angeles would not need its share for years to come. In the end, the project would not save Los Angeles if there was ever a serious drought. Instead, it enabled growers to continue using hundreds of thousands of acre-feet of surplus water that cost them almost nothing. This enabled many growers to expand their acreage beyond a level that is sustainable without the surplus water.
Chapter 8 returns to the Colorado Basin, where some of the greatest water disputes continued to occur, especially between California and Arizona. Denying a neighbor water in the West was akin to declaring war. In the 1930s, these disputes almost caused a physical battle between the two states. The then governor of Arizona deployed the state’s 158th Infantry Regiment and Arizona National Guard to prevent the construction of any dams on Arizona soil. The governor knew that the Bureau was scoping out possible dam sites. If the water had been going to Arizona, this might have been a different picture, but Arizona was fearful that California would continue to try and take more and more water from the river.
While a war between the two states has not happened yet, there have been numerous legal and congressional battles, one of which could spell doom for Arizona. California’s clause in CAP all but ensures the state will someday receive all water from this project. The Colorado Basin will likely go into permanent drought. Once this happens, California will receive every single drop of water that was supposed to go to Phoenix, Tucson, and the farmers in between. This chapter highlights the “West’s cardinal law: that water flows toward power and money” (296). California’s anti-CAP lobbies, at the time powerful water lobbyists, were able to stall the project in Congress long enough that Arizona gave in.
Chapter 9, meanwhile, turns to how the Carter administration attempted to gain control of and curb Congress’s spending on water projects and dam building. Through this chapter, Reisner further reinforces the notion that “water projects are a kind of currency” in Congress (308). Senators would vote against legislation for school lunch programs and jobs programs, which would actually help Americans, yet vote for $20 billion Corps of Engineer projects that impacted far fewer Americans. Congressional members included these water projects in omnibus public works bills to ensure that the President had a much harder time vetoing the bill. During several times in Carter’s term, he was forced to sign bills that went against his attempts to curb the gluttonous water policy. By doing so, he was also able to pass other legislation that he felt was important. The only item that was slowly halting Congress’s water projects spending was the ballooning national debt, to which these projects contributed.
Chapter 10 returns to California, where Reisner continues to show how politicians used underhanded tactics, including ones designed to spread fear among their constituencies, to build pet water projects. For California’s politicians, a reoccurring tactic was to make Los Angelenos believe their city might run out of water. However, projects like the Peripheral Canal that were supposed to bring water to the city typically sent most of the water to farmers. These farmers were not in dire need of the water. Rather, they used it to expand their acreage well beyond sustainable limits outside of the contract.
Here again, Reisner’s central theme regarding the precariousness of the West’s water situation comes to light. Water is not going to current sustainable levels of agriculture. Instead, it is going to new fields, yet continued drought, particularly due to climate change, is eminent for this region of the United States. The vicious cycle of finding water will continue until California and other western states cut back water consumption levels. Given the region has had 150 years to realize this, it seems unlikely that this will happen anytime soon, something which Reisner also seems to hint at.